Overall, I would say he did very well, and the presentation reflects substantial improvement for the Economic Analysis of the BDCP. It was certainly much improved over the June presentation, and I commend David for the enormous amount of work he has completed, and his clear and professional presentation and answers to the many questions. It wasn't perfect, and I have a few new concerns, but they are outweighed by the improvements.
Notable improvements since the last time include:
·
The discussion of the arguably fictional regulatory certainty benefit was minimal, and the enormous estimates of its value were nowhere
to be seen.
·
Also gone was the conclusion statement that
the BDCP is clearly worthwhile to the water agencies since that depended on
the regulatory certainty benefit. [Update: I should note that he did not give any bottom line conclusions, for or against.]
·
And most notably, the BDCP is now saying that
they are going to do a complete statewide benefit-cost analysis after refusing
for years.
While the regulatory certainty benefit was gone, there
were two other notable changes in the benefits analysis that concern me because they are blowing up the
benefits estimates to help justify the tunnels. These are 1) increasing the time horizon
and 2) lowering the discount rate. Both
would draw significant complaints in a peer review, and are notably inconsistent
with the approach used in the California High-Speed Rail benefit-cost analysis. I believe the HSR comparison is critically important because these are the 2 controversial mega infrastructure projects on the state's policy agenda, and they should be analyzed consistently. Time Horizon: Rather than estimating benefits of conveyance only up to 2050 (28 years of operations), Dr. Sunding is now extending the benefits to infinity (yes forever). While cutting off at 2050 was too short, extending the benefits analysis to infinity is erring in the opposite direction.
Here is what the CA HSR B-C analysis says about the same issue (p.8).
Benefits and costs are typically evaluated for a period that includes the construction period and an operations period ranging from 20-50 years after the initial project investments are completed. Given the permanence and relatively extended design life of high-speed rail investments, longer operating periods, and thus, evaluation periods are applicable.I support the use of a relatively long 50 year time span after project completion, but extending benefits to infinity in an infrastructure B-C analysis seems nuts. However, it wouldn't make much of a difference if the discount rate weren't so low, which brings me to the second issue.
For the CA HSR BCA, the evaluation period includes the relevant (post-design) construction period during which capital expenditures are undertaken through 2080...
which is approximately 47 years beyond project completion for the scenario with the longest construction period.
Discount Rate: Dr. Sunding is using a 2.275% discount rate, justified by a recent Army Corps statement that I haven't seen and current, historically low interest rates. This is down from the 3% discount rate used in his initial estimates this summer. While I am sympathetic to using something lower than the traditional 7% rate, this 2.275% assumption could get hammered in a peer-review, even if it has been approved by a federal government agency.
Current interest rates on bonds are being extraordinarily influenced by unprecedented Fed intervention and the lingering effects of a global financial crisis. I don't think you can argue that low U.S. treasury rates in the current market signal that somehow the social rate of time preference or the opportunity cost of public funding (discount rate) has dramatically declined. And what are the appropriate interest rates to guide the discount rate selection? While Federal Treasury borrowing rates are historically low, credit is still extraordinarily tight, and many individuals, businesses and state and local governments are finding it difficult to borrow at any interest rate. The appropriate opportunity costs for the BDCP is connected to who is bearing those opportunity costs, and the federal government has made it pretty clear that they are not paying for the BDCP. Many of the costs are going to be passed through directly to households through rate increases, not added to the Federal debt, so I could make an argument that real interest rates on personal loans (even credit cards) are as relevant as the current rate on Treasuries. Other BDCP costs are slated for the California General Fund through a General Obligation Water Bond. I don't think the opportunity costs of utilizing the state general fund are at historic lows. If anything, the opportunity cost of state funding is at a historic high, and the state hasn't even sold billions of already voter approved bonds due to market and budget conditions - even though interest rates are historically low. California is a state that needed a temporary tax increase (Prop 30) to pass to avoid cutting 3 additional weeks off the school year, is releasing criminals early, and cutting public health and other key services due to lack of funds. Given that the Governor has defined school days as the margin in the state budget, I could argue that the social return on investment for time in school would be the appropriate discount rate (opportunity cost).
Probably more relevant is the other mega-project financed with a combination of general fund dollars and other sources, high-speed rail. CA HSR used a 7% real discount rate for their benefit-cost analysis (p. 6). HSR actually used 4% in their initial draft B-C analysis, but moved it up to 7% in the final draft in response to criticism in the peer review. So, I would suggest that if HSR couldn't get a 4% discount rate past peer review when interest rates were equally low in 2011-12, his 2.275% assumption is going to be a tough sell. Personally, I think 7% is probably too high, and would have recommend running both the HSR and BDCP B-C studies using 3% and 6% discount rates. Dr. Sunding should perform some sensitivity analysis and prove that his results are robust to the HSR assumptions about time horizons and discount rates, and aren't just the result of assuming an infinitely lived project and a super low discount rate.
I am also still a little concerned about his approach to the seismic risk. However, I will note that he toned down the rhetoric about this since the summer, and signaled some openness to considering alternative ways to reduce the consequences of a seismic event. So this area of concern is also more positive and I have hope something good will eventually emerge. I don't think there is any doubt that his analysis will show that the earthquake benefits are much less important to justifying the project than water supply benefits. In fact, it already does.
As always, the criticisms take more space than the compliments, so I should note that I think his work in the critical urban water supply and several other areas is outstanding. I think some of the folks in the audience do not appreciate what is involved here. While I have wanted to smack him occasionally over the years (the feeling is mutual I'm sure), I have a lot of respect for Dave Sunding and remain convinced he is the best choice to lead this very important job.
Really, the biggest key to his benefit-cost analysis of the tunnels is defining a good no-tunnel alternative instead of a comparing the tunnel alternatives to a crappy, no-action, status-quo strawman. The no-tunnel alternative has to be a BDCP option, meaning that it includes the necessary habitat and through-Delta flows and water operations to satisfy the ESA. I see no reason why a no-tunnel alternative can't have comparable "regulatory assurance" benefits, environmental benefits, and even the potential water supply benefits from the "decision tree" as a tunnel alternative. Finally, at least one no-tunnel BDCP alternative, and arguably even the tunnel BDCP alternatives, should include significant seismic levee upgrades.